StudentShare
Contact Us
Sign In / Sign Up for FREE
Search
Go to advanced search...
Free

Relationship between Income Distribution and Firm Size - Essay Example

Cite this document
Summary
"Relationship between Income Distribution and Firm Size" paper examines the proposition that unequal income distribution is essential for rapid accumulation and growth because the rich save and invest a greater proportion of their income than the poor.  …
Download full paper File format: .doc, available for editing
GRAB THE BEST PAPER97.1% of users find it useful
Relationship between Income Distribution and Firm Size
Read Text Preview

Extract of sample "Relationship between Income Distribution and Firm Size"

Running Head: INCOME DISTRIBUTION Relationship between Income Distribution and Firm Size of the of the Relationship between Income Distribution and Firm Size Introduction Trends related to income inequality in the United States have received considerable attention recently. While the extent of inequality and the degree of change depend on how it is measured, there is general agreement that overall inequality in the distribution of income and wealth in the U.S. has been increasing since the 1970's. Throughout the 1980's, overall employment growth in nonmetropolitan areas lagged behind metropolitan growth, while the earnings gap increased. In every rural industrial sector, the percentage of workers whose full-time wage was insufficient to raise a family of four above the poverty line increased in the 1980's. Recent years have witnessed increased polarization in income levels both among countries and among various income groups and classes within countries. Rapid and steady growth in developing countries is clearly necessary to close their income gap with the advanced industrial countries and improve standards of living. There may be some scope for raising income through reallocation of existing resources, but restoring rapid growth depends in large part on raising the rate of capital accumulation. Experience shows that while rapid growth as such may not lead to a significant improvement in income distribution in the short to medium term, it is indispensable for attaining a more balanced pattern of distribution in the longer term. More importantly, policies can be designed so as to strengthen the forces making for greater equality while promoting growth and absorbing the surplus labor that prevails in many developing countries. Firm Size The ability of market mechanisms and locally-based initiatives to provide for the economic well-being of those persons at the low end of the income distribution is questionable. In practice, much of the concern for distributional issues is lost in the transition from an academic or policy discussion to the implementation of local economic development programs (Leigh 1995). While there is some evidence that economic growth will benefit low income workers (Bartik 1991), there is also a possibility that explicit local redistribution policies may create local comparative disadvantage (Bartik 1992). More work is needed to understand the distributional characteristics of private markets. If greater responsibility for the economic welfare of citizens defaults to the community level, it becomes important to focus attention on income distribution at the scale of local labor markets. Further, to the extent local economic development policy can affect the activity levels of targeted production sectors, it also has an effect on distributional patterns. Thus, it becomes important to understand the implicit distributional biases of local policy in its promotion of selected economic activities, and to question whether explicit distributional objectives can be incorporated into local economic development programs. Other important factors influencing the distribution of income are the institutional structures that organize wealth. Institutions are the entities that engage in transactions, own assets, and incur liabilities (Pyatt 1988, 1991). Conventional institutional specification is as households, enterprises, and government. Within this general framework, institutional accounts can be disaggregated in considerable variation to permit the study of policies (development strategies, tax systems, laws) that influence distributional patterns. For example, SAM research has disaggregated household accounts by landholding status (Adelman et al. 1988; Lewis and Thorbecke 1992), while other research disaggregated forest enterprises by land tenancy group (Marcouiller et al. 1995). Thus, the process of wealth accumulation consists of two parts: the generation of income through productive activities, and its distribution to households. This distribution is fundamentally influenced by variable structural patterns in production and policy processes. Several points related to the approach taken in this research are illustrated in Figure 1. Shown is a simplified flow diagram of the SAM used in this research. The center column shows the major SAM accounts used to track income flow, and the infusions and leakages are shown on either side. To understand processes associated with the generation of income, attention is focused on those factors contained in the box labeled income generation. It is generally assumed an economic infusion changes the level of productive activities with the result to regional income observed as value added. Firm Size and Income Distribution The study of income distribution is different, and may be more complicated. Following the Rose et al. (1988) conception, it is possible to investigate the distributional impacts associated with the structure of productive activities (industry mix) in several ways. The first would be to look at the connection between production and value added, requiring the transformation of value added into factor returns (returns to land, labor, and capital). Additionally, disaggregating labor returns by occupation also provides insight into the distribution of income. More complex yet would be tracking income into the institutional matrix within which households are a sub-account. The difficulty with this approach is differentiating the processes associated with the generation of income from those associated with income distribution. While both the study of income generation and distribution must account for infusions and leakages, the investigation of distributional processes focuses on the connection between factor income generation and its distribution to local households. Some policies might directly alter levels of productive activities, as in the case of an import substitution program. Here, it may be appropriate to follow the full flow of income from production to households. If the research is concerned with the study of distributional impacts associated with other types of policies (taxes, transfer programs), the focus can be more narrowly defined to a subset of the structures within the endogenous economy. Alternative specifications of institutional income opens additional possibilities for asking questions related to land reform, land tenancy, or local development strategies. By carefully tracking how factor income is reorganized by institutions, accounting for the additional infusions and leakages, and observing the resulting distribution in the household account, it is possible to more clearly identify the distributional effects of the policy without being obscured by processes associated with income generation, or the numerous external factors affecting income flow. To date, considerable attention has been devoted to the generation of income from production sectors, while little attention has been paid to subsequent processes associated with the distribution of income. A second important reason to employ an alternative regional specification is to improve understanding of rural economic conditions. Rural areas typically serve as the periphery for central places in functional economic regions. The focus of a functional economic area is invariably the center, with the result that economic impacts occurring in the periphery may be "washed-out" by the relatively more prominent effects associated with the dominant economic structures found in the center. Thus, policies targeting rural conditions are better understood with models built explicitly for the study of rural areas. Models that account for income and trade flows between the dominant economic centers and their rural periphery, while maintaining the essential focus of the rural areas will be more illuminating regarding the effects of rural development policies. Finally, from the standpoint of policy implementation, there are practical reasons to create models of regions that are delineated by non-economic factors. Regional self-identification arising from natural resource endowments, historical antecedents, local administrative relationships, population homogeneity, and other factors can make models built on the basis of alternative criteria more useful to local policy-makers and the results of local policy analysis more likely to be implemented. The practical effect of using alternative boundaries as the basis for economic modeling, however, presents a number of difficulties. It becomes increasingly important to accurately account for income and trade flows between the rural area under study and nearby economic centers. Similarly, secondary data may not be available for the desired boundaries. Among production costs are payments made to the owners of productive factors (value added). All income accrues to the owners of productive factors. To determine income distribution, it was necessary to specify the share each factor contributed to the net return of productive activities and then determine the share of each productive factor owned by each institution and household income group. IMPLAN reports income in the form of value added. Value added consists of employee compensation, proprietary income, and other property income plus indirect business taxes. This categorization does not allow separation of value added into returns to factors of production. The method used to establish factor shares involved allocating net factor returns first to labor, then to capital and land based on an imputed rate of return (Marcouiller et al. 1996, Leatherman 1995, appendix 2). Institutions provide the transition between productive activity and household income. Institutions serve the functional purpose of providing the organizational scheme for allocating factor income to household income groups. Thus, institutional specification organizes the income generated from production sectors in a fashion that permits observation of distributional patterns associated with development strategies. In this case, the organizational scheme considers how factor income generated by productive activities being targeted by local economic development programs will be distributed. This matrix also distributes factor taxes, the regional in- and out-flow of factor payments, and institutional transfers, providing a more precise accounting of the distribution of income earned from productive activities to household income groups. As local governments in rural areas assume more responsibility for their economic well-being, it becomes beneficial to learn more about the characteristics of private markets at a regional scale. A common objective of local development policy is to enhance opportunities for those in need. To the extent local policy can affect productive activities in targeted economic sectors, such policies will have de-facto distributional consequences that alter the ability to achieve development objectives. To understand the de-facto distributional characteristics of rural development sectors and local development policy, a social accounting matrix analysis was shown to be a useful tool for describing how changes in sectors important to rural areas affect household income groups. Information related to income distribution can not reduce income disparities or local conditions of poverty. However, concern related to distributional impacts encourages the re-examination of assumptions related to local economic development policy, and more careful consideration of the beneficiaries of development assistance. By bringing distributional issues to the policy arena, the community is taking steps toward making rational choices about its economic development. Conclusion The proposition is then examined that unequal income distribution is essential for rapid accumulation and growth because the rich save and invest a greater proportion of their income than the poor. It is shown that, while the rich may indeed save and invest proportionately more than the poor, the same degree of inequality among countries is often associated with different rates of accumulation, or that a given rate of accumulation is compatible with lower or higher inequality. Thus, accelerating growth does not necessarily require a greater concentration of income in the hands of the rich. The relationship between inequality and accumulation is greatly influenced by the extent to which profits are saved and invested. An examination of sources of capital accumulation shows that corporate profits are often the principal source of investment in industry, while the contribution of voluntary household savings to productive investment is relatively small. However, the extent to which profits are saved and reinvested varies considerably among countries. It is argued that high retention and reinvestment of profits foster accumulation and growth at minimal inequality in terms of personal income distribution. What distinguishes East Asian newly industrializing economies (NIEs) from other developing countries is not so much an exceptionally high rate of household savings as a considerably higher propensity of corporations to save and invest profits. References Adelman, I.J., E. Taylor, and S. Vogel. 1988. Life in a Mexican village: A SAM perspective Journal of Development Studies, 25 ( 1): 5-24. Bartik, T.J. 1991. Who benefits from state and local economic development policies. Kalamazoo MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute. -----. 1992. The effects of state and local taxes on economic development: A review of recent research. Economic Development Quarterly, 6( 1): 102-110. Brown, D.L., and K.L. Deavers. 1989. The changing context of rural economic policy in the United States. In research in rural sociology and development: Rural labor markets. Volume 4, edited by W.F. Falk and T.A. Lyson. Greenwich CT: JAI Press. Christopherson, S. 1993. Explaining the new spatial inequality: Regulatory policy and local economic capacity. In Population change and the future of rural America: A conference proceedings, edited by L.L. Swanson and D.L. Brown. Staff Report No. AGES 9324. Agricultural and Rural Economy Division, Economic Research Service. Washington DC: U.S. Department of Agriculture, 79-92. Galston, W.A. 1993. Rural America in the 1990's: Trends and choices. In Population change and the future of rural America: A conference proceedings, edited by L.L. Swanson and D.L. Brown. Staff Report No. AGES 9324. Agricultural and Rural Economy Division, Economic Research Service. Washington DC: U.S. Department of Agriculture, 10-22. Gorham, L. 1993. The slowdown in nonmetropolitan development: The impact of economic forces and the effect on the distribution of wages. In Population change and the future of rural America: A conference proceedings, edited by L.L. Swanson and D.L. Brown. Staff Report No. AGES 9324. Agricultural and Rural Economy Division, Economic Research Service. Washington DC: U.S. Department of Agriculture, 60-78. Gottschalk, P., and S. Danziger. 1993. Family structure, family size, and family income: Accounting for changes in the economic well-being of children, 1968-1986. In Uneven tides: Rising inequality in America, edited by S. Danziger and P. Gottschalk. New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 167-193. Haslag, J.H., and L.L. Taylor. 1993. A look at long-term developments in the distribution of income. Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, First Quarter: 19-30. Hewings, G.J.D. 1985. Regional input-output analysis. Beverly Hills CA: Sage Publications. Holland, D., and P. Wyeth. 1993. SAM Multipliers: Their decomposition, interpretation and relationship to input-output multipliers. Research Bulletin XB1027. College of Agriculture and Home Economics Research Center. Pullman WA: Washington State University. Hoppe, R.A. 1991. Defining and measuring poverty in the nonmetropolitan United States using the survey of income and program participation. Social Indicators Research, 24( 2): 123-151. Kaldor, N. 1956. Alternative theories of distribution. Review of Economic Studies, 23(1955-56):83-100. Keuning, S.J., and W.A. de Ruijter. 1988. Guidelines to the construction of a social accounting matrix. Review of Income and Wealth, 34( 1): 71-100. Leatherman, J.C. 1995. The distributional impacts of alternative local development strategies: An application of social accounting matrix analysis. Unpublished PhD. dissertation. Department of Urban and Regional Planning, Madison WI: University of Wisconsin-Madison. Leatherman, J.C., and D.W. Marcouiller. 1997. Estimating tourism's share of local income from secondary data sources. The Review of Regional Studies, 27 ( 1), in press. Leigh, N.G. 1995. Income inequality and economic development. Economic Development Quarterly, 9 ( 1): 94-103. Lewis, B., and E. Thorbecke. 1992. District-level economic linkages in Kenya: Evidence based on a small regional social accounting matrix. World Development, 20( 6): 881-897. Lichter, T.B. 1993. Demographic aspects of the changing rural labor force: Issue brief. In Population change and the future of rural America: A conference proceedings, edited by L.L. Swanson and D.L. Brown. Staff Report No. AGES 9324. Agricultural and Rural Economy Division, Economic Research Service. Washington DC: U.S. Department of Agriculture, 136-150. Madden, M., and A.B. Trigg. 1990. Interregional migration in an extended input-output model. International Regional Science Review, 13 (1&2): 65-86. Marcouiller, D.W., D.K. Lewis and D.F. Schreiner. 1996. Timber production factor shares by forest tenancy group. Land Economics 72( 3):358-369. Marcouiller, D.W., D.F. Schreiner and D.K. Lewis. 1993. Constructing a social accounting matrix to address distributive economic impacts of forest management. Regional Science Perspectives 23 ( 2):60-90. -----. 1995. Distributive economic impacts of intensive timber production. Forest Science, 41( 1): 122-139. Mazie, S.M., and M.S. Killian. 1991. Growth and change in rural America: The experience of the 1980s and prospects for the 1990s. In Rural community economic development, edited by N. Walzer. New York: Praeger, 1-19. Miller, R.E., and P.D. Blair. 1985. Input-output analysis: Foundations and extensions. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, Inc. Minnesota IMPLAN Group. 1993. Micro IMPLAN User's Guide: Version 91-F. St. Paul MN: Minnesota IMPLAN Group. O'Connor, A. 1992. Modernization and the rural poor: Some lessons from history. In Rural poverty in America, edited by C.M. Duncan. New York: Auburn House, 215-233. Peterson, W.C. 1991. Transfer spending, taxes, and the American welfare state. Boston MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Pyatt, G. 1988. A SAM approach to modeling. Journal of Policy Modeling, 10( 3):327-352. -----. 1991. Fundamentals of social accounting. Economic Systems Research, 3( 3):315-341. Pyatt, G., and A. Roe. 1977. Social accounting for development planning with special reference to Sri Lanka Cambridge, Great Britain: Cambridge University Press. Pyatt, G., and J.I. Round. 1979. Social accounting matrices for development planning. Review of Income and Wealth, 23( 4): 339-364. ----- (eds.). 1985. Social accounting matrices: A basis for planning. Washington DC: The World Bank. Richardson, H.W. 1985. Input-output and economic base multipliers: Looking backward and forward. Journal of Regional Science, 25( 4):607-661. Rose, A., B. Stevens and G. Davis. 1988. Natural resource policy and income distribution Baltimore MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. Rural Sociological Society. 1993. Persistent poverty in rural America. Task Force on Persistent Rural Poverty. Boulder CO: Westview Press. Sahota, G.S. 1978. Theories of personal income distribution: A survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 16( 1): 1-55. Schweikhardt, D.B. 1992. Assessing the research framework and institutional context for rural development policy: Discussion. Southern Journal of Agricultural Economics, 24( 1):117-119. Subramanian, S., and E. Sadoulet. 1990. The transmission of production fluctuations and technical change in a village economy: A social accounting matrix approach. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 39( 1):131-174. Tickamyer, A.R., and C.M. Duncan. 1990. Poverty and opportunity structure in rural America. Annual Review of Sociology, 16:67-86. U.S. Department of Commerce. 1990. 1990 U.S. Census of Population and Housing. Bureau of the Census, STF 3, P80. Extracted from CD ROM by the Applied Population Laboratory. Madison WI: University of Wisconsin-Madison. -----. 1994. Personal income by major sources and transfer payments by type. Regional Economic Information System, 1969-1992. (CD-ROM). Bureau of Economic Analysis. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office. Weicher, J.C. 1995. Changes in the distribution of wealth: Increasing inequality Review, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, 77( 1):5-23. Wisconsin Department of Industry, Labor and Human Relations. 1993. Wisconsin unemployment compensation. Extracted from ES202 data files by the Applied Population Laboratory. Madison WI: University of Wisconsin-Madison. Read More
Cite this document
  • APA
  • MLA
  • CHICAGO
(“Income Distribution Essay Example | Topics and Well Written Essays - 2000 words”, n.d.)
Retrieved from https://studentshare.org/sociology/1505502-income-distribution
(Income Distribution Essay Example | Topics and Well Written Essays - 2000 Words)
https://studentshare.org/sociology/1505502-income-distribution.
“Income Distribution Essay Example | Topics and Well Written Essays - 2000 Words”, n.d. https://studentshare.org/sociology/1505502-income-distribution.
  • Cited: 0 times

CHECK THESE SAMPLES OF Relationship between Income Distribution and Firm Size

Marketing Strategies for R200 Revola Smart Phone

The paper "Marketing Strategies for R200 Revola Smart Phone" highlights that for quality control and avoiding counterfeiting the company intends to release controlled consignments into the market.... The software configuration and setup shall be developed in such a way that cloning does not happen....
10 Pages (2500 words) Research Paper

SMEs in Chinas Textile and Clothing Industry

Within the past decades or so paralleling the growing integration and liberalization of the world trading system and the recognition that exporting is an attractive way of tapping foreign market opportunities, investigation of factors which are critical to firms' export success and performance has been the focus of increased research attention....
32 Pages (8000 words) Essay

Japanese Distribution System

The term "distribution system" refers to a system of interdependent organizations that are involved in carrying out marketing activities in order to create and deliver value in the form of products and services to intermediate and final customers or clients.... These systems are also referred to as marketing channels, distribution channels, business channels and/or value chains. ... he Japanese distribution system accommodates the cultural and economic concerns of business establishments in Japan....
16 Pages (4000 words) Essay

Sales and Distribution Management

Group task moderates the relationship between group process and group effectiveness.... This paper ''Sales and distribution Management'' tells us that christmas is the busiest season on the calendar.... There is no doubt that most importers have contracted for the distribution of their goods several weeks earlier.... The situation, as it currently stands, is that our company had contracted with a sales/distribution company to both sell and distribute 3,000 tones of our toys across the United Kingdom in time for Christmas....
16 Pages (4000 words) Assignment

E-Marketing Strategy-Business Issues

In the second model, there is no need for an inventory and shipments can be made from the factory maintained a central warehouse or other distribution points at a lower cost.... The case study "E-Marketing Strategy-Business Issues" states that Marketing is a complex and costly exercise and there are both traditional brick and mortar stores and online stores that cater to customers....
12 Pages (3000 words) Case Study

Poverty, Income Inequality, and Community Crime Rates

and compares the Gini coefficient and indicators of poverty, such as unemployment and income distribution, in the areas of concern.... This assertion relies on the premise that offenders and victims of crime are vulnerable groups that have a likelihood of increasing in size during tough economic conditions, especially in areas with poor income distribution.... In the early 1970s and late 1980s, a range of important literature reviews failed to arrive at a clear consensus regarding the association between income inequality in various states and violent crime....
11 Pages (2750 words) Research Paper

Income Inequality and Wellbeing

This term could also be used to point out the cross-sectional distribution of income and wealth at specified periods of time or spread over time.... income disparity is one of the metrics of economic disparity that refers to how income is distributed among individuals in a group, among groups present in a population or among the different countries of the world.... income inequality usually varies between societies, periods of....
8 Pages (2000 words) Literature review

Financial Modelling - Relationship between Market Risk and Stock Return

The paper 'Financial Modelling - relationship between Market Risk and Stock Return' is a thoughtful example of a finance & accounting report.... The paper 'Financial Modelling - relationship between Market Risk and Stock Return' is a thoughtful example of a finance & accounting report.... The paper 'Financial Modelling - relationship between Market Risk and Stock Return' is a thoughtful example of a finance & accounting report.... According to the CAPM model, there is a linear relationship between the stock return and beta (market risk)....
16 Pages (4000 words)
sponsored ads
We use cookies to create the best experience for you. Keep on browsing if you are OK with that, or find out how to manage cookies.
Contact Us