StudentShare
Contact Us
Sign In / Sign Up for FREE
Search
Go to advanced search...
Free

The Use of Higher Co-Payments to Reduce Expenditure on Health Care - Term Paper Example

Cite this document
Summary
The author examines the use of higher co-payments to reduce expenditure on health care, the main methods of payment of health sector organizations such as hospitals and gives recommendations on the method of paying publicly funded hospitals for inpatient care in the U.K…
Download full paper File format: .doc, available for editing
GRAB THE BEST PAPER95.8% of users find it useful
The Use of Higher Co-Payments to Reduce Expenditure on Health Care
Read Text Preview

Extract of sample "The Use of Higher Co-Payments to Reduce Expenditure on Health Care"

Health Economics The use of higher co-payments to reduce expenditure on health care: Co-payments are generally used patient-level inducement for adjusting the demand for services and the use of pointless care (Health Care Costs-Fact Sheet). Cost-sharing approaches such as co-payments, coinsurance, and charges that fluctuate with the total number of expenditure of prescriptions filled are extensively used to control expenses’ growth in drug proposals. Co-payments decrease the use of important and less important drugs and may be associated with unfavorable health consequences (Kephart 2007, 328). The use of cost sharing in health care is often controversial, generating academic debate about its effectiveness as a policy tool and political debate about its feasibility. Economic theory triggers arguments put forward for both sides of the discussion. Neo-classical economists state that the utilization of health services surpasses communally beneficial standards when health care expenses are entirely covered by insurance. Insurance decreases the marginal expenditure of individuals who are utilizing health services because it efficiently lowers the cost of these services to zero. Accordingly, insured individuals will take advantage of as much health care as they would if the health care were free of charge (Thompson and Mossialos n.d., 227). Many studies reveal that when confronted with higher expenses, individuals will procure less care. Preferably, higher co-payments would damp only the use of low-worth care (Chernew and Fendrick n.d., 17). The probable risks of higher cost sharing are most sensitive for seniors and disabled persons.  Since these people use the majority of health services and medicines, their out-of-pocket expenses for co-payments would be maximum and they are the ones most probable to evade or delay required health care owing to cost problems (Ku 2003).  When individuals have to disburse fees or co-payments for health care, the quantity can be so high concerning earnings that it results in “economic catastrophe” for the person or the household. Such high spending health care facilities signify that individuals have to reduce their necessities, for instance, food and clothing, or are incapable of paying for their childrens schooling. Every year, around 44 million families, or above 150 million people, all through the world face appalling expenditure, and roughly 25 million families or over 100 million individuals are pressed into poverty by the requirement to disburse for services. Moreover, the effect of these out-of-pocket payments for health care goes away from catastrophic expenditure alone. Many individuals may choose not to utilize services, merely as they cannot afford either the unswerving expenses, for example, consultations, medications and laboratory experiments, or the indirect expenses, such as conveyance and special food. Poor families are likely to descend even further into scarcity due to the unfavorable impacts of illness on their incomes and general interests. An apprehension of policy-makers is to defend people from monetary catastrophe and insolvency as a result of utilization of health services. World Health Organization (WHO) has recommended that health related spending should be observed as disastrous whenever it is beyond or equivalent to 40 per cent of a households non-continuation income, i.e. earnings accessible after basic requirements have been met. However, nations may wish to utilize a diverse cut-off point in locating their national health strategies (Designing Health Financing Systems to reduce catastrophic health expenditure 2005, 1). Catastrophic spending does not mechanically fade away with rising earnings. National health financing schemes must be planned not only to let people to access services when they are required, but also to defend households from monetary catastrophe, by decreasing out-of-pocket expenditure. In the long term, the goal should be to expand prepayment instruments, such as through communal health insurance, tax-supported financing of health care, or some combination of prepayment devices. Programs that exclusively center on the poor may not attain the desired results. The most common deficiencies are that the advantages package incorporates only restricted services and those co-payments are high. Additionally, in practice it has been observed that the recipients of such programs are not always poor. Moreover, there are other disadvantaged crowds who should be regarded, for example, the old, the handicapped and those with unceasing health conditions and unusual diseases. These groups are often simpler to target (Designing Health Financing Systems to reduce catastrophic health expenditure 2005, 3). The judgment on the standard of out-of-pocket payments has to equilibrate the requirement to protect individuals from economic catastrophe and to guarantee that the structure is efficient. While patients are sheltered by insurance or tax-based structures and make no, or little, out-of-pocket payments, experience proposes that there may be more than one recommendation and over-utilization of pharmaceuticals. This has an impact mainly on total health related spending and the financial feasibility of the system. On the other hand, the higher the level of out-of-pocket payments the less the guard against the financial hazards of ill health and the lower the admission to desirable services, mainly among the poor. It is not essential to apply the same expenditure sharing level to all inhabitants. Exclusions or lower rate could be applied to susceptible population groups (Designing Health Financing Systems to reduce catastrophic health expenditure 2005, 4). The neoclassical economic model presupposes that supply and demand are separately established, but as health care providers are typically better knowledgeable than patients, often acting as patients’ mediators, they have substantial potential to control both the kind and amount of health services utilized. In practice, most choices about the utilization of health services are made by contributors and are not rooted in patients’ individual evaluation of potential advantages. For instance, a US study noted that higher co-payments for prescription medicines were linked with lower spending on medicines when doctors did not have any financial incentive to control drug spending, but had little impact when doctors had financial inducements to control drug expenditure. In both cases, lower spending eventually resulted from decreases in utilization. However, owing to information asymmetries, it would seem preferable for the recommending doctor to make choices about which kinds of medicines patients can do without. The neo-classical economic model also fails to keep in mind the journey, time and psychological expenses that people may incur when utilizing health services (Thompson and Mossialos n.d., 228). A Danish study observed that the augmentation in co-payments for antibiotics in consequence of the deductible initiated in 1988 had a major impact on the prescribing prototypes of general practitioners (GPs), leading to a 13 per cent cut in the utilization of antibiotics in North Jutland County amid 1995 and 1996. The impact was high for broad-range antibiotics; for instance, the use of tetracycline fell by 42 per cent while the consumption of constricted spectrum penicillin remained steady (Thompson and Mossialos n.d., 223-234). Cherkin, Grothaus and Wagner (1989) reviewed the beginning of a $5 co-payment rate for state workers registered in an HMO in Washington State in the mid-1980s, in relation to federal workers; they find an ample decrease in office appointments (Gruber 2006, 9). Selby, Fireman and Swain (1996) assessed the beginning of a crisis room co-payment for some companies insured by the Kaiser Permanente HMO scheme in the early 1990s, proportionate to a control assembly of those companies who did not perceive this co-payment rise. They find an important decline in crisis room utilization, with no proof of unfavorable impacts on health. Chandra, Gruber and McKnight (2006) find that an enhancement in co-payment from $0 to $10 for office appointments lowered the pace of office appointments by 18 per cent among the aged, and that an increase in prescription drug co-payments of $6 on average declined prescription drug use by 7 to 19 per cent. Thus, the conclusion that medical use is price responsive holds the test of time. Thus, while there are several other disputes for and against Health Savings Accounts (HSAs), a key tip to recognize is that all expenditure-sharing for patients is not produced equally: high deductible preparations are a substandard arrangement to plans with earnings-related patient co-payments (Gruber 2006, 13). The main methods of payment of health sector organizations such as hospitals: For those policy creators, regulators, buyers, and contributors of health care who are thinking of alternative payment preferences for hospitals in their nations, this guide offers basic information on one alternative commonly referred to as case-related repayment or repayment for every discharged patient. Case-related repayment is a hospital compensation arrangement in which a hospital is reimbursed for each released inpatient at rates probably established for organizations of cases with analogous clinical report and reserve requirements. Case-based repayment rates mirror historical expenses of both individual hospital and the total system of hospitals. However, unlike historical funding, this device makes inducements for hospitals to decrease costs per case. The transition to cost-related reimbursement symbolizes the main force of hospital financing improvements over the past 20 years. This disbursement instrument draws the notice of reformers who want their nationwide hospital sectors to be more prolific, receptive to consumer anticipations, and flexible to alterations in the demand for services (Telyukov 2001, 1). Case Mix Payment Rates are costs at which each hospital is repaid for treating a patient in a given case combination group. A rate is decided by multiplying the case combination cost by the hospital-detailed base rate. In the early phases of implementation, the hospital’s base price is determined exclusively using the hospital’s standard expenditure per case. However, to promote effectiveness, the hospital base rate may be computed by merging the hospital-specific average expenses with the network-extensive average costs. Outlier Payments complement the repayment of hospitals for cases with unusually high span of stay. However, outlier payments may also be under a standard case combination group rate if span of stay is considerably under the historical average for an exact case combination group (Telyukov 2001, 4). Many Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) nations have recently sketched to execute a DRG-based potential hospital payment scheme in an effort to meet numerous policy goals, incorporating: 1) a better share of payments and incomes across services and hospitals; 2) financial inducements to progress “technical competence” at the individual hospital stage; 3) an augmentation in overall scheme efficiency so as to meet provincial or country-level spending caps; and 4) other communal policy goals. Most of the OECD structures recently executed have pursued the US Medicare model for framing and developing for every DRG payments. While the Medicare Prospective Payment System (PPS) has attained a level of success in controlling hospital expenditures, the system undergoes some deficiencies regarding resource allotment for an All-Payer population, alignment of inducements across hospitals and payers, and other payment fairness deliberations. Over 35 years the Maryland All-Payer Hospital Rate Setting structure has been a pacesetter in the domain of DRG-based potential hospital payment structure. While the Maryland system has many attributes that are close to the Medicare PPS, it was planned to cover an All-Payer inhabitants and be receptive to unique provincial and hospital specific circumstances. The Maryland System is the first scheme to slot in the utilization of All Patient Refined (APR) DRGs into its payment methods. The System also uses a unique payment arrangement that more efficiently supports the inducements of both hospitals and disbursers (Murray 2007). PPS utilizes fundamentally fixed payments rooted in the diagnosis-associated group (DRG) of a hospital access. This policy alteration reflected the use of principles of the best repayment to hospital price rule. Hospitals still obtained more payments for patients anchored in characteristics that forecasted higher treatment expenses, but DRGs were intended to lessen the connection between a hospital’s real resource utilization and payments for a specific patient. Consequently, hospitals had to stand more of the expenses of treating a given patient more rigorously (McClellan 1997, 92) The commission’s hospital payment structure, which became effective from October 1, 2006, is saving South Carolina owners and insurance firms nearly $100 million per year, as said by analysts of the commission. According to statistics supplied by the health and demographics part of the state’s Office of Research and Statistics, the figure of employees’ reimbursement cases treated by hospitals and ambulatory operation centers refused 8.6 percent amid 2000 and 2006. Over the same phase, inpatient charges for employees’ reimbursement cases augmented almost 141 percent, whilst outpatient charges augmented by approximately 225 percent (Hospital payment system saves $98 million per year, n.d.). Medicare DSH payments should be established from the Average Adjusted Per Capita Cost (AAPCC) payments for organized health care schemes. Presently, DSH payments are not made of the AAPCC, which denotes that these payments are given to organized-care plans that do not offer low-earnings or uncompensated care, rather than to the sanatoriums that do. Since the Medicare DSH program was meant to reimburse hospitals, not organized -care schemes, for the low-earnings care they offer, these payments should go directly to sanatoriums (Fagnani and Tolbert 1999, vii). Recommendations on the method of paying publicly funded hospitals for inpatient care in U.K.: In case of a developed nation like United Kingdom, the Mississippi Division of Medicaid can certainly change the technique it employs to compensate hospitals for inpatient care. Under the new technique, the Medicaid payment for a particular inpatient residence will be strictly tied to the perception, or case mix, of the inpatient residence. Sanatoriums that house sicker patients can anticipate higher payments, which should develop admission to care. Under the new technique, all hospitals will be compensated similarly for related patients. If they improve competence, they will keep the cutbacks. Each stay is allocated to a single DRG with a single compensation. DRGs are systematized so that each DRG includes stays that are analogous both clinically and in terms of hospital reserves utilized (A new inpatient hospital payment method for Mississippi Medicaid 2007, 2). Under the new system, a hospital will obtain final compensation for a stay soon after it presents a claim (A new inpatient hospital payment method for Mississippi Medicaid 2007, 3). References: 1. “A new inpatient hospital payment method for Mississippi Medicaid”, May 15, 2007. Available at: http://www.medicaid.ms.gov/Documents/HospitalInpatientFAQs.pdf (Accessed on Aug. 27, 2009). 2. Chernew, Michael. E. and A. Mark Fendrick. “Value Based Insurance Design Insuring Health Care Cost Debate” Vision for the Future of the U.S. Health Care System, n.d. Available at: http://www.soa.org/library/essays/health-essay-2009-chernew.pdf (Accessed on Aug. 27, 2009). 3. “Designing Health Financing Systems to reduce catastrophic health expenditure” World Health Organization. Department of Health Systems Financing. Health Financing Policy, 2005. Available at: http://www.who.int/health_financing/pb_2.pdf (Accessed on Aug. 26, 2009). 4. Fagnani, Lynne and Jennifer Tolbert. “The Dependence of Safety Net Hospitals and Health Systems on the Medicare and Medicaid Disproportionate Share Hospital Payment Programs, Nov. 1999. Available at: http://www.commonwealthfund.org/~/media/Files/Publications/Fund%20Report/1999/Oct/The%20Dependence%20of%20Safety%20Net%20Hospitals%20and%20Health%20Systems%20on%20the%20Medicare%20and%20Medicaid%20Disproportion/fagnani_dependsafetynethospitals_351%20pdf.pdf (Accessed on Aug. 27, 2009). 5. Gruber, Jonathan. “The Role of Consumer Co-payments for Health Care: Lessons from the RAND Health Insurance Experiment and Beyond” The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation, Oct. 2006. Available at: http://www.kff.org/insurance/upload/7566.pdf (Accessed on Aug. 26, 2009). 6. “Health Care Costs-Fact Sheet” U.S. Department of Health and Services, n.d. Available at: http://www.ahrq.gov/news/costsfact.htm (Accessed on Aug. 27, 2009). 7. “Hospital payment system saves $98 million per year”, n.d. Available at: http://www.wcc.sc.gov/NR/rdonlyres/39207BA1-2E5C-454B-AAF5-BD5B391EDF15/0/HospitalPaymentSystemSavesMillions.pdf (Accessed on Aug. 27, 2009). 8. Kephart, George. “Effect of Co-payments on Drug Use in the Presence of Annual Payment Limits” Impact of cost sharing of medication use, Vol. 13. No. 2, June 2007. Available at: http://www.ajmc.com/media/pdf/AJMC07junPrt2_Kephart328to34.pdf (Accessed on Aug. 26, 2009). 9. Ku, Leighton. “Charging the Poor more for health care: Cost-sharing in Medicaid” Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, May 7, 2003. Available at: http://www.cbpp.org/cms/index.cfm?fa=view&id=1938 (Accessed on Aug. 27, 2009). 10. McClellan, Mark. “Hospital Reimbursement Incentives: An empirical analysis” Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume 6, Number 1, Spring 1997. Available at: http://mitpress.mit.edu/journals/JEMS/McClellan.pdf (Accessed on Aug. 27, 2009). 11. Murray, Robert. “DRG-based hospital payment system design and related issues.”, July 6, 2007. Available at: http://www.healtheconomics.org/congress/2007/pre-conference/murray-hospital-payment-design.pdf (Accessed on Aug. 27, 2009). 12. Telyukov, Alexander. “Prospective Case-Based Payment for Hospitals: A Guide with Illustrations from Latin America” LAC HSR Health Sector Reform Initiative, Mar. 2001. Available at: http://www.lachsr.org/index.php?option=com_docman&task=doc_download&gid=39&Itemid=.(Accessed on Aug. 27, 2009). 13. Thomson, Sarah and Elias Mossialos. “Influencing demand for drugs through cost sharing”, n.d. Available at: http://www.euro.who.int/document/e83015_14.pdf (Accessed on Aug. 26, 2009). Read More
Cite this document
  • APA
  • MLA
  • CHICAGO
(The Use of Higher Co-Payments to Reduce Expenditure on Health Care Term Paper, n.d.)
The Use of Higher Co-Payments to Reduce Expenditure on Health Care Term Paper. Retrieved from https://studentshare.org/macro-microeconomics/1557257-health-economics
(The Use of Higher Co-Payments to Reduce Expenditure on Health Care Term Paper)
The Use of Higher Co-Payments to Reduce Expenditure on Health Care Term Paper. https://studentshare.org/macro-microeconomics/1557257-health-economics.
“The Use of Higher Co-Payments to Reduce Expenditure on Health Care Term Paper”. https://studentshare.org/macro-microeconomics/1557257-health-economics.
  • Cited: 0 times

CHECK THESE SAMPLES OF The Use of Higher Co-Payments to Reduce Expenditure on Health Care

The Business of Health Care

The Business of health care The concept of quality care in the healthcare industry is of utmost importance for the wellbeing and financial survival of the patient.... hellip; Politicians and their advisers engage in continuous debate over the role of the federal or state governments in the process, while business and economic considerations drive massive restructuring on the delivery and finance of the health care services.... Despite all these changes, hospitals, nursing homes, individual health care professionals, insurance companies, medical centres, and managed care organizations must progressively make decisions and take actions concerning the business aspect of their service (Clarke, 2005:449)....
12 Pages (3000 words) Essay

Impact of Cost of Health Care on the US Economy

nbsp; A look into the year 2005, expenditure on health care was about $2 trillion or $6,697 per capita, which correspond to 16% of the GDP.... One notable impact of increased expenditure on health care is the decline in general economic growth.... Therefore, gaining an understanding of how increased expenditure on health care affects the economy requires evaluation through various dimensions (Eaton et al, 2002).... An example is a situation where the government reduces its expenditure on health care by reducing the eligibility for public health insurance....
7 Pages (1750 words) Assignment

US Healthcare Costs and Lessons for Rapidly Developing Countries

hellip; This is starkly evidenced by the difference in health care costs the US spending 8,508 for every citizen, while Canada and the UK spend $ 4,522 and $ 3,405 respectively.... The WHO reported that the government spent more health care as a GDP percentage and on healthcare per capita in 2012 than any other country in the world (Neumann 50).... This paper will provide recommendations for containing the high costs of health care, as well as lessons that other rapidly developing economies can learn from the situation in the US....
7 Pages (1750 words) Essay

Health Care Spending

The major reason why the United States spends so much on health care is that the U.... health care spending in the United States is increasing at a rate as never before.... Total health care spending represented 16 percent of the gross domestic product (GDP).... health care spending in the United States far exceeds the expenditure of any other industrialized country.... The United States, with it wealth, education, technology, and power seems not to have a grasp on its health care spending as it spends twice as much pr capita and yet does not provide what other countries offer to their citizens....
5 Pages (1250 words) Essay

Cost of Dying and effects of healthcare delivery system

The number of Americans has risen with the need for addressing long-term care and focusing on a comfortable aging process, safe housing and end-of-life care.... Their self-care actions could change their quality of life.... Their These can mostly be achieved by designing long-term care facilities or homes to suit their mental and physical requirements.... Hospice care is another major facility which caters to the dying during their last few months of life when they are in any terminal or chronic illness and when curative treatment is not feasible....
23 Pages (5750 words) Thesis

Financing Health Care in the US

The aim is proposed to be achieved through initially presenting the current status of health care in the U.... prior to delving into the intricate issues and concerns that the government is trying to address to improve its present stance… The paper describes the present status of US health care, examines the components of health care sector expenditures and the suggestions and recommendations of various in conjunction with one's personal assessment....
5 Pages (1250 words) Term Paper

Current and Future Economic Issues of the Healthcare Sector

There are two reasons why the United States invests hugely in health care: first is a rising demand for health care and, second is waste and inefficiency.... health care market.... Five of the most… healthcare sector today and will continue to do so in the near future are the following: (1) physician-induced demand; (2) defensive medicine; (3) third-party payment; (4) rapid technological change; and (5) cost This paper thoroughly analyzes these five factors that are affecting the demand and supply, as well as the costs, of health care services in the United States....
10 Pages (2500 words) Coursework

Health Insurance

As you learn about health care delivery in the United States, it is important to understand the various models of health insurance to develop a working knowledge as you progress through the course.... The following matrix is designed to help you develop that knowledge and assist… in understanding how health care is financed and how health insurance influences patients and providers as important foundational information for your role as a future health care worker....
5 Pages (1250 words) Coursework
sponsored ads
We use cookies to create the best experience for you. Keep on browsing if you are OK with that, or find out how to manage cookies.
Contact Us